During the exploitation of the product, a major portion of management energies is devoted to realizing the best possible profitability by means of competitive pricing, promotion, aggressive selling, control of costs, etc. However, there remains an important need for concern within the problem of strategy. The central problem is when and how to introduce new products into the firm's portfolio.
In many industries demand can be stimulated and life cycle effectively expanded through a combination of three types of strategic change: gaining an increasing share of the market, introducing improved products which create a replacement demand, and introducing the product to markets not previously invaded. An expanded life cycle is illustrated in Figure 5.
The product-market changes introduced at points A, B, C have a very strong synergy with the original product market. They address the same type of demand, the same type of customer; they use familiar product technology and rely on the existing organizational capabilities. Thus, this expansion type of strategic change is a part of the natural dynamics of the firm. It is automatically stimulated by pressures from competition, demands from customers, and ideas generated within the firm.
The significant fact is that strategic expansion will take place in most firms regardless of whether the management devotes special attention to guiding and controlling it. Whether such processes will be most efficient when allowed to develop through the natural dynamics of the firm is altogether a different issue. Generally, without explicit planning and control the process will be much less efficient: the timing of introduction will not be optimal, nor will the choice of the means of expansion. Nevertheless, change does take place and assures survival of firms in environments which are not strongly competitive.
The rate of strategic expansion will be determined by the budgets allocated to R & D and to market development. The maximum possible rate is determined, in part, by the resources of the firm. However, there is a natural limit, determined by the capacities of the firm, beyond which additional budget allocations produce declining effectiveness and eventually deterioration in effectiveness of expansion. When pressed to expand at excessive rates, the responsible organizations within the firm begin to suffer from corporate indigestion.
If it is an objective of the management to expand substantially in excess of the rate which can be efficiently generated within the firm, a frequently used alternative is to expand through acquisition from outside. This may include purchase of products developed by others, licensing and acquisition of other firms. Firms which have historically expanded from within do not have built-in organizational capabilities for handling acquisitions. Therefore, expansion by acquisition will not take place, unless the top management first triggers it off and, secondly, allocates appropriate resources and assigns responsibilities for its execution.
In addition to controlling the rate (through budgeting) and the manner (though choice of external versus internal route) of strategic expansion, top management can significantly influence a very strong synergy with the original product market. They address the same type of demand, the same type of customer; they use familiar product technology and rely on the existing organizational capabilities. Thus, this expansion type of strategic change is a part of the natural dynamics of the firm. It is automatically stimulated by pressures from competition, demands from customers, and ideas generated within the firm.
General management is the only level at which information, authority, and the necessary degree of detachment are available to permit a comparison of conflicting claims and a rational allocation of the firm's resources among the various expansion possibilities. Therefore, formulation of strategy is a general management responsibility.
A basically different type of strategic change occurs when the new product-market entries break with tradition and introduce the firm into an unfamiliar area of demand and of product technology. In the normal course of strategic expansion, the responsible departments of the firm (particularly the R & D department) will generate such novel product-market ideas occasionally. Unless the firm has established skills and procedures to exploit these ideas, the only way in which they can be implemented is through intervention by top management. The management is likely to give consideration to them only if they promise truly outstanding profitability. Such unplanned departures from the basic product-market position of the firm represent unplanned diversification. Usually they are random events which seldom have a major impact on the firm.
When a firm deliberately seeks a significant alteration in its product-market position it may undertake planned diversification (6, Chapter 7). This change may be triggered off by adversity such as, for example, a sudden breakthrough by competition which obsolesces the firm's product markets (see Figure 4 for illustration), or it may be caused by inevitable saturation and decline of the current markets, or it may be brought about by a management objective to grow faster than the present prospects permit. The logistic process of the firm is not capable of producing large-scale diversification on the strength of its current dynamics and capabilities. New products and markets must be invented or discovered, new logistic processes must be introduced for manufacture and distribution of these products, new management systems instituted new resource inputs provided. In other words, this change requires redesign and reconstitution of the firm. But this cannot occur without direct involvement by top management of the firm. Therefore, planned diversification will occur only if top management attention is triggered off in the manner described in the last section.
Through appropriate reorientation, the R & D and the market development department of the firm can be directed by management to find and create diversification opportunities. However, the responsibility for diversification usually comes on top of the prior responsibility for expansion. A conflict arises between the two types of activity in which strong pressures favor expansion against diversification. The responsible departments are under continued pressure from the sales department, from the manufacturing department, from customers, from competition, to devote their effort to strengthening and expanding the present products and markets of the firm. As a result, unless management provides continued incentives, influence, and specially earmarked resources for diversification, expansion tends to become the central internal development activity.
Aside from allocation of effort, there is a problem of the direction of diversification. While expansion is to a large extent self-directed by the dynamics of the firm, diversification has no natural direction. Left to themselves the responsible departments, particularly the R & D department, will develop ideas which follow individual interests and technical competence of influential investigators and managers. These directions may not bear any relationship to one another, nor to the capabilities and resources of the firm.
The distinctive feature of the upper 'top management' level is that it has responsibility and control over the entire process of innovation. This group includes the chief officer of the firm as well as his division managers. Together they have a unique perspective of the firm as a whole: of its environment, of its capabilities of conflicting claims on its resources. Their major contribution to innovation arises out of this perspective. It includes the following activities:
(1) Maintenance (either informally through personal contacts, or formally through special staffs) of surveillance of the condition of the firm and of the environmental conditions surrounding it.
(2) Allocation of top management resources among the perceived needs and opportunities (for example, among strategic, administrative, and operating problems).
(3) Development of objectives and of product-market strategy for the firm, allocation of appropriate resources, and assignment of responsibilities for implementing the strategy.
(4) Design of the overall management and logistic systems for the innovative process.
(5) Analysis and selection of specific product-market moves proposed by middle management. (Since this decision requires a firm-wide perspective it should not be delegated.)
(6) Commitment of the firm to exploitation of developed products and providing operating policies, resources, and responsibility.
At the middle management level the responsibilities include the following:
(1) Expanding strategic and policy guidance into specific operation plans, budgets, and procedures.
(2) Design of appropriate logistic and management sub-systems.
(3) Communicating and providing leadership in execution of plans.
(4) Monitoring and evaluating the results, instituting appropriate control actions.
(5) Submitting to top management information and action recommendations at appropriate points in the innovative process.
(6) Providing top management with information relevant to and necessary for effective performance of top management function.
In the problem of strategy the last function acquires particular importance. Effective formulation of strategy requires that top management have available to it the perspective of trends, threats and opportunities to the firm from the vantage point of the senior marketing manager, and particularly, the senior R & D manager. Thus, in a very real sense, both of these managers are responsible for strategy formulation.
The preceding discussion describes the most complete management involvement in the strategic change process which can be found in a business firm. It also contains a prescriptive element in the fact that we have allocated top and middle management responsibilities on the principle that decisions should be made at the lowest levels at which the appropriate and necessary information is available. In terms of observable behavior of firms, it is easy to see why in many firms strategic process can and does proceed with minimal participation from top management. So long as, through the budgeting process, top management allocates resources for innovation, innovation can be managed at middle management levels. The transition between the respective stages of the logistic process becomes more permissive and automatic, strategic action is mainly confined to expansion, the strategy is an implicit one of ' natural ' unplanned extrapolation of the firm's history.
As we suggested throughout the paper, it does not follow that a fully developed system for managing strategic change is the optimal solution for all firms. For a given firm the optimal solution should be arrived at, initially, through determining the firm's strategic needs, secondly, through determining the resources of the logistic process to be devoted to innovation, and thirdly, analyzing the nature of the firm's innovative logistic process and hence its management needs. Throughout this paper we have suggested various hypotheses which can be used as guidelines for this process.